Categories
Conferences Copyright Copyright Theory History of Intellectual Property Injunctions Innovation Intellectual Property Theory Internet Inventors Patent Law Patent Theory Remedies Uncategorized

IP Promotes Progress by Securing the Individual Liberty of Inventors and Creators

This is the third in a series of posts summarizing CPIP’s 2014 Fall Conference, “Common Ground: How Intellectual Property Unites Creators and Innovators.” The Conference was held at George Mason University School of Law on October 9-10, 2014. Videos of the conference panels and keynote will be available soon.

The second panel of CPIP’s 2014 Fall Conference analyzed the common moral case for copyrights and patents. The panel was moderated by Professor Chris Newman (George Mason University School of Law). Two of the panelists, Professor Mark Schultz (CPIP, and Southern Illinois University School of Law) and Professor Eric Claeys (George Mason University School of Law) explained the theoretical and normative principles underlying the moral case for intellectual property. The other two panelists, Dr. Ken Anderson (Thermaquatica) and David Lowery (musician, producer, and lecturer at the University of Georgia), then showed how those principles play out in practice.

Professor Schultz noted that the moral case for intellectual property is often overshadowed by (or outright ignored in favor of) the economic case. But in addition to being economically valuable, intellectual property serves important moral functions by enabling artists and inventors to live free and flourishing lives. Intellectual property fosters economic independence, enables the creation of a private sector, and supports political freedom. Patents and copyrights give an important set of choices to creators and inventors, enabling them not only to survive, but also to thrive. As such, intellectual property is a moral right that facilitates individual liberty. While the economic justifications for copyrights and patents remain important, it is equally important not to lose sight of their strong moral underpinnings.

Professor Claeys discussed the moral case for injunctive relief against IP infringement. Starting from a traditional property law perspective, he explained that remedies (such as injunctive relief) are essential in reinforcing and vindicating property rights. Just as with traditional property, copyrights and patents confer exclusive control to their owners to secure to them the value of their productive labors. By protecting copyright and patent owners’ discretion over the deployment of their property, injunctions protect their moral rights in the fruits of their labors. Claeys further noted that this labor-based understanding of intellectual property could inform the balance of equities discussed in eBay v. MercExchange, filing significant gaps in the Supreme Court’s reasoning and likely leading to a different conclusion regarding licensing companies’ ability to obtain injunctions.

Anderson and Lowery addressed the role of IP in their respective fields. Dr. Anderson discussed how patents were crucial to his ability to obtain investors for his green tech company. He invented a new, environmentally-friendly technology to convert “coal, biomass and other organic solids into low molecular weight products.” Being able to protect the value of his work through patent protection (he filed multiple rounds of patents all over the world) has been essential to his company’s success and his ability to commercialize his invention.

Lowery discussed how the lack of copyright enforcement in the digital era has affected the music industry, leading to an environment where internet platforms thrive, but the artists and creators who fuel the value of those platforms struggle mightily to make ends meet. In many ways, musicians are worse off now than they were in the 1950s (an era that s well-known for the exploitation of musicians). Nonetheless, he expressed hope that the third decade of the Internet could embrace legal and technological innovations that make it a better place for artists.

In sum, the panelists illustrated the fundamental moral importance of intellectual property, which applies equally to inventors’ patent rights as it does to artists’ copyrights. Intellectual property isn’t just about economic incentives. IP also promotes progress by securing the individual liberty of inventors and creators.

Categories
Biotech Commercialization Conferences Copyright Innovation Intellectual Property Theory Inventors Uncategorized

The Common Economic Case for Patents and Copyrights

This is the second in a series of posts summarizing CPIP’s 2014 Fall Conference, “Common Ground: How Intellectual Property Unites Creators and Innovators.” The Conference was held at George Mason University School of Law on October 9-10, 2014.  Videos of the conference panels and keynote will be available soon.

The opening panel of CPIP’s 2014 Fall Conference examined the common economic case for patents and copyrights. Unfortunately, IP policy discussions often include a false narrative that intellectual property produces monopolies that harm innovation and economic growth.  The panelists, Troy Dow (Disney), Professor Stan Leibowitz (University of Texas at Dallas), Jon Santamauro (Abbvie), and Professor Jay Kesan (University of Illinois College of Law), highlighted how this narrative, in fact, ignores the essential role that intellectual property serves in enabling the creation, development, and commercialization of both inventions and creative works.

Kesan explained how patents provide economic benefits from both an ex-ante and ex-post perspective. Ex-ante, a strong patent system provides incentives to create, invest in R&D, and finance further innovation. While there are other ex-ante motivations to invent (such as a first mover advantage, the ability to secure trade secrets, and reputational advantages), Kesan argued that innovation is best facilitated ex-ante by a combination of all of these incentives plus the incentives created by patents. The ideal system incorporates a heterogeneous mix of these incentives to invent—in the absence of patents the level of disclosure decreases and innovation slows down.

Patents also provide numerous ex-post benefits. Patents facilitate coordination with producers and perform important signaling functions. They additionally allow for important private ordering by giving inventors increased control over who uses their invention and under what circumstances. In many industries, this is essential to collaboration, interoperability of products, and the aggregation of complementary benefits.

Jon Santamauro discussed the role of patents in the pharmaceutical industry. The exclusive property rights created by patents encourage R&D and serve as a crucial catalyst for new discoveries and businesses.  Patent protection is particularly important in the pharmaceutical industry due to the high-risk, lengthy, and costly process necessary to develop new, safe, and effective drugs.

Pharmaceutical companies developing new drugs screen thousands of potential compounds over 6-7 years of testing to gain FDA approval, at an average cost of about $1.2 billion per drug. The reasons for the high R&D costs?  Out of 10,000 initial molecules tested, only 6 go to clinical trials, and of these, only 1 is approved by the FDA for use in the healthcare market.  Of the 1 out of 10,000 drugs that make it to market, only 2 out of every 10 medicines produce enough revenues to recoup the initial high costs of R&D and also provide revenue to invest in more R&D. In short, pharmaceutical and biotech firms face very high risk—high R&D expenditures and very few market successes.  Strong IP protection helps offset this risk and encourages further investment and research.

Leibowitz explained that one of the primary criticisms of copyright—that it grants a monopoly, and that monopolies are intrinsically bad for society—is utterly thoughtless. A property right is, by definition, a monopoly of sorts. This criticism is an indictment of property rights on the whole, including real property rights.  This is even more inapt to copyright, as copyright does not restrict entry and does not provide an economic monopoly.

Leibowitz also addressed the common argument that IP isn’t necessary because inventors and creators would continue inventing and creating even if they didn’t get to own the fruits of their productive labors.  While some innovative and creative activity would undoubtedly continue, many innovators and creators do not simply create for creations sake. They need salaries (like everyone else), and strong IP rights allow them to capture the value of what they produce.

Finally, Troy Dow highlighted the benefits of strong copyright protection in the movie industry. Bringing a film to market involves substantial risks that many people do not appreciate.  He explained that studios perform the same market function as venture capitalists: they invest in  films at the birth of the original idea and then provide financing all the way through the final showing in movie theaters. This financing comes from banks, other investors, or other studios in order to spread the risk. Dow analogized a new film project to a new startup company, as each new film has its equivalent of a CEO (producer), COO (director), and thousands of employees and independent contractors.  And just as with startup companies, everyone must be paid before the film makes a single cent in revenue.

A single film can cost over $200 million to produce. While a particularly big hit can gross over $350 million after long-term distribution (including on-demand and DVD sales), only 4 out of every 10 movies recoup their investment at the box office. Copyright thus serves the vital function of making it possible for studios to make substantial, upfront investments with the hope of a return on this investment and a sufficient profit to reinvest in further film projects.

Disney’s IP is enormously valuable and is the dominant driver of their business. Even though only $6 billion of Disney’s $45 billion in revenues last year came directly from movie revenue, the movies, including the stories they tell, are at the heart of the Disney experience.  The movies form the basis for other products, media networks, theme parks, and licensing. A strong copyright regime allows studios like Disney to keep producing both creative works and the myriad other products and experiences that so many of us enjoy.

Together, the four panelists illustrated that the economic foundations of IP are equally applicable to the creative industries as they are to the innovation industries.  By securing for inventors and creators the value of their productive labors, IP provides the economic bedrock of our creative and innovative economy.

Categories
Commercialization Conferences Copyright Copyright Licensing Copyright Theory Economic Study High Tech Industry History of Intellectual Property Injunctions Innovation Intellectual Property Theory Internet Inventors Law and Economics Patent Law Patent Licensing Patent Litigation Patent Theory Remedies Software Patent Uncategorized

Intellectual Property Unites Creators and Innovators

This is the first in a series of posts summarizing CPIP’s 2014 Fall Conference, “Common Ground: How Intellectual Property Unites Creators and Innovators.” The Conference was held at George Mason University School of Law on October 9-10, 2014. Videos of the conference panels and remarks, as well as panel summaries, will be available soon.

Introduction by Professors Adam Mossoff and Mark Schultz

Common Ground: How Intellectual Property Unites Creators and Innovators

The creative industries and innovation industries have much in common, but too often this is overlooked. Both industries engage in brilliant intellectual work to bring new products and services into the world, both take great risks to commercialize this work, and both depend on intellectual property – copyrights (for the creative industries) and patents (for the innovation industries). Unfortunately, most accounts of these two industries emphasize their differences and frequently portray them in conflict.

This conference will explore the common ground shared by these two dynamic industries, focusing on the similar values secured by their patents and copyrights and thus their common policy goals and commercial developments.

It should be unsurprising that these two industries share much in common. The work of inventors and artists is much the same. We see hints of this in their respective aspirations. Engineers, for example, often talk of seeking “elegant” or “beautiful” solutions to the technological problems they face. Artists also strive to innovate technically in how they create their works, as demonstrated with much panache in the recent documentary, Tim’s Vermeer. Many creators apply their prodigious talents to both art and invention.

One may think of a Steve Jobs today as exemplifying this truth, but history is replete with examples. Leonardo da Vinci also comes to mind, the quintessential Renaissance Man. In the 19th century, Samuel Morse invented the telegraph, but he was also a successful artist and in fact he developed the telegraph while working as a well-known Professor of Art at New York University.

In modern America, Walt Disney has defined much of our culture not just with his artistic creations, but also with his innovative technological creations in movies, theme parks and products. More recently, filmmakers George Lucas and James Cameron have cast large shadows in popular culture, but their contributions to filmmaking technology may prove even more enduring and pervasive.

These and many other examples are unsurprising when one considers that art and technology both result from the same source: productive intellectual labor.

As the work of artists and inventors is at heart the same, so is the moral and economic case for securing property rights to them. Artists and inventors deserve to own the fruits of their productive labors. In protecting these labors, intellectual property rights secure to them their liberty and their careers. These rights thus fuel the vast economic activity that drives the innovation economy – bringing to market the products and services that ensure full and flourishing lives for them and for the rest of us as well.

Too often, though, the creative and innovation industries are portrayed as being at odds. One popular narrative today – in both scholarly and popular accounts – is that technology disrupts the creative industries, forcing copyright owners to adapt. This is a myopic account of their relationship that ultimately creates a false picture. In truth, creativity and innovation – secured by copyrights and patents – constantly spur each other to greater heights.

The true story of creativity and innovation is more properly viewed as a virtuous circle.

Recording and broadcast technology, for instance, gave musicians and other performers their first worldwide audiences, whose demand for ever-more entertainment and information spurred further improvement and expansion of technology. The invention of the electric guitar, spurred by a series of patented improvements, enabled blues and rock ‘n’ roll, which in turn pushed further developments in music and recording technology.

The Internet certainly created much disruption, but it also has been a fountainhead of creativity. To take just one example, streaming of original, creative content enables television viewers to enjoy storytelling as never before, bringing about what some are now calling a Second Golden Age of Television.

Our technological devices, such as smartphones and iPads, would not be so well loved and so ubiquitous without the games, music, and video content they deliver to hundreds of millions of people the world over.

The common ground and shared aspirations of creators and innovators is clear, but rarely appreciated in the din of today’s policy debates.

Thus, our Annual Conference this year considers afresh the common goals, challenges and needs of the creative and innovation industries. Many distinguished speakers with extensive knowledge and experience in both fields will address how intellectual property rights represent the bedrock of this common ground. We hope that you will enjoy what promises to be enlightening discussion.

**Panel summaries coming soon**